<code id="0vk3o"><ol id="0vk3o"></ol></code><track id="0vk3o"></track>
<p id="0vk3o"><strong id="0vk3o"><small id="0vk3o"></small></strong></p>

  • <td id="0vk3o"></td>
      1. <pre id="0vk3o"></pre>

        指导
        网站地图
        英国作业 美国作业 加拿大作业
        返回首页

        英国论文指导-非对称变动对英国房地产价格的影响-The asymmetric volatility of house p

        论文价格: 免费 时间:2012-04-16 14:49:55 来源:www.hsltc.com 作者:留学作业网

        英国论文指导-非对称变动对英国房地产价格的影响The asymmetric volatility of house prices in the UK
        Abstract
        Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to show an indication that the asymmetric volatility between house price movement may account for the defensiveness of the housing market.
        Design/methodology/approach – First the UK nation-wide house price data from the last quarter
        (Q4) of 1955 to the last quarter of 2005 are used and then the most suitable mean and variance
        equations to estimate the conditional heteroscedasticity volatilities of the returns of house prices are
        selected. Second, a variable that examines the leverage effect of volatility is incorporated into the
        model. The GJR-GARCH model is used.
        Findings – The results of the empirical test show that while the lagged innovations are negatively
        correlated with housing return, that is when there is bad news, the current volatility of housing return
        might decline.
        Research limitations/implications – The results indicate that the volatilities between house
        prices moving up and moving down are asymmetric.
        Practical implications – The results show that there is a defensive effect in the UK housing market
        during the data periods used.
        Originality/value – Although several articles have documented that there is heteroscedasticity and
        autocorrelation in the volatilities of real estate prices, few of those papers have noted one of the most
        important advantages of the housing market, its defensiveness, from the viewpoint of volatile
        behavior.
        Keywords Real estate, Prices, Cyclical demand, Residential property, United Kingdom
        Paper type Research paper
        Introduction
        Over the past few decades, the highly volatile behavior of house price series has been
        recognized in a number of studies, and several empirical articles have tried to capture
        the short-term adjustment process of house prices (Meen, 1990; Drake, 1993; Heiborn,
        1994; Eitrheim, 1995; Abraham and Hendershott, 1996; Malpezzi, 2001, Kapur, 2006).
        Most of these studies try to model price behavior based on factors related to the
        housing demand and supply, and further use traditional regression for analysis. But,
        most of these economic models do not come up with satisfying performance capturing
        the volatile behavior of the housing markets.
        Several methodologies and models are now being used in order to reduce the
        heteroscedasticity problems of house price and estimate this volatile process. For
        example, house prices were always converted to natural logarithms in empirical tests
        in previous house price studies in order to reduce the heteroscedasticity variance
        problems in ordinary least squares (OLS) regression. On the other hand, Hendry (1984)
        and Giussani and Hadjimatheou (1990) have tried to model the volatility by using
        The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
        www.emeraldinsight.com/0263-7472.htm
        PM
        27,2
        80
        Received December 2007
        Revised October 2008
        Accepted January 2009
        Property Management
        Vol. 27 No. 2, 2009
        pp. 80-90
        q Emerald Group Publishing Limited
        0263-7472
        DOI 10.1108/02637470910946390
        non-linear specifications to capture extreme movements in house prices. Hendry (1984)
        used a cubic approximation function, calculated as the cubic term of house price
        changes. Giussani and Hadjimatheou (1990) used both square and cubic terms to
        capture the rapid adjustment of house price.
        Because high volatility is very common in financial data, the family of ARCH
        (Engle, 1982) and GARCH (Bollerslev, 1986) models were developed and are widely
        applied to model the variance of financial variables. These types of models allow the
        conditional variance of a series to depend on the past realizations of the error process
        and simultaneously model the time-dependent mean and variance. Because of their
        excellence in capturing volatility, these types of models are applied to various areas,
        including housing studies (Dolde and Tirtitoglu, 2002; Miller and Peng, 2006; Tsai et al.,
        2008).
        However, the volatility characteristic of housing markets might be distinct from
        that of other financial markets, and it is surprising that few previous studies have
        documented the main features of housing market volatility. However, similar studies
        have been done in the securities market, and several articles have indicated that there
        is a leverage effect in the volatile behavior of securities; that is, the impact on future
        assets’ return when unexpected bad news is announced is larger than when unexpected
        good news is made public. Black (1976) pointed out that an unexpected decline of stock
        prices can result in an increase of the ratio of debt to equity, leading to an increase in
        the financial risk of corporations and eventually a higher fluctuation of securities’
        price. But it is not yet known whether there is also a leverage effect in the volatility of
        housing market.
        The main purpose of this paper is to study the volatility properties of the UK house
        price series, in particular, to examine whether or not there is a leverage effect in the
        volatility of house prices. To consider the asymmetric volatility, the GJR-GARCH
        model is used. Glosten et al. (1993) and Zakoian (1994) suggest a GJR-GARCH model in
        which the relation between lagged error term and current volatility may be dependent
        on the sign of lagged error. The error is the difference between true value and
        estimated value, hence, when lagged error is negative, it means that unexpected bad
        news has come out, whereas when lagged error is positive, it indicates good news.
        Therefore, the asymmetric volatility model, GJR-GARCH, can measure the concept of
        leverage effect empirically. Following the work of Glosten et al. (1993) and Zakoian
        (1994), we can determine the important characteristics of the volatile behavior in the
        housing market.
        This paper is structured as follows. The next section describes the methodologies,
        while section three shows a review of our data and tests using time-series properties.
        Estimation results are reported and discussed in section four, and the results of
        robustness test are showed in section five. The last section provides a summary of the
        main findings and draws some conclusions.
        Methodology
        To capture volatility of house prices, we employed the ARCH-type model to model the
        volatility of house price changing over time, and used the GJR-GARCH model to see
        whether or not there is a leverage effect in the variance process of house price. These
        two kinds of models are discussed below:
        Volatility of
        house prices
        81
        Modeling volatility of house prices over time: ARCH and GARCH models
        Many economic time-series do not have constant mean and volatility. Engle (1982)
        showed that it is possible to simultaneously model the time-dependent mean and
        variance through the widely known Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic
        (ARCH) model. This allows the conditional variance of a series to depend on the past
        realizations of the error process. Bollerslev (1986) extended Engle’s original work by
        developing the Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (GARCH)
        model that allows for both autoregressive and moving average components in the
        heteroskedastic variance. We briefly illustrate the features of these two models in the
        following.
        ARCH model. Let yt denote the return of house price at time t. The error process is
        obtained from a first-order autoregression for yt following the ARCH (q) model, and it
        can be specified as:
        yt ¼ a0 þ a1yt21 þ 1t
        1t
        V~j t21Nð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þX
        q
        i¼1
        ai12
        t2i
        where q is the number of ARCH terms, and ht is the heteroskedastic conditional
        variance, which is correlated with the lagged error terms.
        GARCH model. If the error process obtained from a first-order autoregression for yt
        follows the GARCH(p,q) model then it can be specified as:
        1t
        V~j t21Nð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þX
        p
        i¼1
        biht2iX
        q
        i¼1
        ai12
        t2i
        where ht is the heteroskedastic conditional variance, correlated with the lagged error
        terms and conditional variance.
        Asymmetric volatility in the housing market: GJR-GARCH
        With the ARCH-type models we have shown above, the heteroskedastic conditional
        variance is symmetrically correlated with the lagged error terms. Since it does not
        matter whether the lagged error is negative or positive, the relation between the
        heteroskedastic conditional variance and the lagged error terms is a constant
        coefficient, namely, ai . Hence, those models may not be appropriate for a series that has
        asymmetric volatility or one that arises from markets in which there is a leverage
        effect. To deal appropriately with the series having asymmetric characteristics, the
        Glosten, Jagannthan, and Runkle (GJR)-GARCH model is used. The features of the
        GJR-GARCH model are briefly described as follows.
        Let yt denote the return of house price at time t. The error process is obtained from a
        first-order autoregression for yt following the GJR-GARCH (p, q) model, and it can be
        specified as:
        PM
        27,2
        82
        yt ¼ a0 þ a1yt21 þ 1t
        1t
        V~j t21Nð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þX#p#分页标题#e#
        p
        i¼1
        biht2i þX
        q
        i¼1
        ai12
        t2i þg12
        t21Dt21
        where Dt21 is a dummy variable, when 1t21 , 0, Dt21 ¼ 1; otherwise, Dt21 ¼ 0. The
        coefficient g represents the asymmetric feature of conditional variance. If the estimated
        results show that g is significantly not equal to zero, it indicates that the volatile
        behavior of house price is not symmetric. The relation between conditional variance
        and lagged error is dependent on whether or not the lagged error is negative. If g is
        positive, a leverage effect exists, because when bad news comes out (i.e. the lagged
        error is negative), the variance will increase. In contrast, if g is negative, an
        anti-leverage effect exists because following bad news (i.e. the lagged error is negative)
        the variance will decline.
        Data description
        We use the UK nation-wide house price data starting from the last quarter of 1955 to
        the last quarter of 2005. All house and new house price data are compared. The data set
        used in our analysis consists of quarterly observations on all house prices (Allph) and
        new house prices (Newph).
        Table I presents a summary of the descriptive statistics for two house price
        variables. It also reports the outcome of tests for stationarity. An Augmented
        Dickey-Fuller (Said and Dickey, 1984) test and a Phillips and Perron (1988) test both
        confirm that two house price variables are I(1). Evidently, the unit-root hypothesis
        cannot be rejected at the 5 per cent significance level for two series in levels. In
        AllPh NewPh
        Variable
        Number of observations 213 213
        Mean 476.77 499.97
        Std dev. 205.43 199.77
        Skewness 1.24 0.72
        Kurtosis 4.79 3.35
        Variables in level
        ADF test 0.79 0.31
        0.99 0.98
        PP test 0.83 0.39
        (0.99) (0.98)
        Variables in differenced
        ADF test 24.85 27.68
        (0.00) (0.00)
        PP test 26.99 28.03
        (0.00) (0.00)
        Notes: One-sided p-values are reported in parentheses
        Table I.
        Descriptive statistics
        Volatility of
        house prices
        83
        addition, tests applied to differenced data favor the stationary alternative for two
        series. To avoid the problem of spurious regression throughout the paper, we use the
        first-difference data to estimate the empirical models.
        To observe the volatility of house prices, Figure 1 plots the quarterly time series of
        two house prices for the sample period. We can observe that the two price series have
        increased in non-monotonic ways during the sample period. The two series seem to
        have changes in volatility, showing up and down movements. Hence, this paper
        emphasizes the volatile properties of house prices.
        Empirical results
        Modeling volatility of house prices over time: ARCH and GARCH models
        Before estimating the house price volatility, we need to determine the mean equation.
        We use the lagged data of house price as the independent variables, and choose the
        model which can minimize the value of Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and
        Schwartz Bayesian Criterion (SBC) to decide the number of lag terms. Due to the
        consideration of the degrees of freedom, only lags of length 1 to 4 are tested. The
        empirical results of different AR models are shown in Table II.
        Table II shows that the AR(1) model for new house prices is the most appropriate
        because these two model selection criteria, derived from the first-order autoregression
        model, perform better than the other AR models. For all house prices, the SBC criteria
        suggest similar results, although AIC suggests that AR(4) might be better. Because the
        SBC is asymptotically consistent, whereas the AIC is biased toward selecting an
        over-parameterized model, we choose the AR(1) model for all housing markets.
        Figure 1.
        House prices in the all
        housing and new housing
        markets
        PM
        27,2
        84
        Before we use the ARCH and GARCH models, it is necessary to test whether or not
        ARCH effects exist in the data. We use the formal Lagrange multiplier test for ARCH
        disturbances, as proposed by Engle (1982), and results of the LM test are shown in
        Table III.
        Table III shows that the disturbances obtained from the first-order autoregression of
        two series are autocorrelated, which means the variance (risk) in the two house markets
        are time dependent. Then, we use theARCHandGARCHmodels to estimate the variance
        of the two series at a particular point in time. We estimate three different ARCH and
        GARCH models to determine the most appropriate model for volatilities of the two
        housing markets. These are the AR(1)-ARCH(1), AR(1)-ARCH(2), andAR(1)-GARCH(1,1)
        models. The results of these three-model estimations are shown in Table IV.
        Three ARCH-family models for two series are estimated and the results are presented
        in Table IV. The estimated coefficients of ARCH and GARCH effects are highly
        significant in each series. The results show that the GARCH model might perform better
        than the other models, since the lower values of AIC and SBC and the innovations are
        closer to being white noise, because the Q statistics and Q-squared statistics are lowest.
        Hence, the AR(1)-GJR-GARCH(1,1) models are used to estimate the leverage effect.
        Furthermore, the three ARCH-family models might not be appropriate for the two house
        markets, because the sum of estimated coefficients describing the relation between the
        conditional variance and the lagged error and lagged variance are larger than one. The
        inappropriateness of these models might because the models do not incorporate the
        asymmetry of volatility. In observing the feature of the volatility, Figures 2and3showthe
        returns of house price and the conditional volatilities as estimated by GARCH (1,1). The
        returns of house price and the estimated volatilities seem to be positively correlated in the
        two markets; that is, there is a higher return with higher volatility and a lower return with
        lower volatility. Hence, asymmetric volatility might exist in the markets. The
        GJR-GARCH model is used to deal with the inference more carefully.
        AR(1) AR(2) AR(3) AR(4)
        All house price
        AIC 7.92 7.93 7.93 7.88
        SBC 7.95 7.98 7.99 7.96
        New house price
        AIC 8.03 8.04 8.05 8.04
        SBC 8.06 8.08 8.11 8.12
        Table II.
        Estimates of AR models
        Lags of length 1 2 3 4
        All house price
        TR2 4.81 7.03 7.11 22.70
        p-value 0.03 0.03 0.07 0.00
        New house price
        TR2 3.04 7.80 12.34 13.32
        p-value 0.08 0.02 0.01 0.01
        Note: H0, there are no ARCH effects
        Table III.
        Results of ARCH
        effect test
        Volatility of
        house prices
        85
        Figure 2.
        Returns and estimated
        conditional volatilities for
        the all house market
        Model ARCH(1) ARCH(2) GARCH(1,1)
        All house New house All house New house All house New house
        Mean equation
        a0 1.44 1.48* 1.76* 1.22* 0.67 0.64
        (0.93) (0.37) (0.89) (0.43) (0.47) (0.48)
        a1 0.66* 0.53* 0.70* 0.59* 0.61* 0.46*
        (0.05) (0.02) (0.05) (0.04) (0.07) (0.08)
        Variance equation
        v0 114.40* 56.38* 75.20 14.22* 0.26 0.58
        (8.67) (10.38) (7.52) (5.70) (0.48) (0.53)
        a1 0.33* 1.61* 0.33* 1.60* 0.15* 0.17*
        (0.12) (0.31) (0.12) (0.28) (0.04) (0.03)
        a2 – – 0.34* 0.44* – –
        – – (0.11) (0.14) – –
        b1 – – – – 0.89* 0.87*
        – – – – (0.03) (0.02)
        Adj R-squared 0.42 0.31 0.41 0.31 0.41 0.29
        AIC 7.89 7.98 7.84 7.84 7.43 7.62
        SBC 7.95 8.04 7.92 7.92 7.51 7.70
        Q(20) 211.79* 46.39* 219.82* 40.49* 131.08* 40.22*
        Q2(20) 58.79* 19.43 47.89* 13.12 26.55 6.50
        Notes: Model: Let yt denote the series of the differenced house price
        yt ¼ a0 þ a1yt21 þ 1t
        1t jVt21
        ~ jNð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þX
        p
        i¼1
        biht2iX
        q
        i¼1
        ai12
        t2i
        * indicates significance at the 5 per cent level; numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Q(20) and
        Q2(20) are the Ljung-Box statistic based on the standardized residuals and the squared standardized
        residuals respectively up to the 20th order
        Table IV.
        Empirical results of
        ARCH-family
        PM
        27,2
        86
        Asymmetric volatility in the housing market: GJR-GARCH
        To see whether or not the conditional volatilities of house prices switch are dependent
        on the news (i.e. bad or good), the GJR-GARCH (1,1) model is used, The results of
        estimations are shown in Table V.
        As we can see in Table V, the coefficient (g) that represents the asymmetric feature
        of conditional variance is very significant, indicating there are asymmetric volatilities
        in both housing markets. Furthermore, both g are negative, indicating that there are
        anti-leverage effects in two markets. This is because when there is bad news (i.e. the
        lagged error is negative) the variance will decrease, which is in contrast with the
        findings of those empirical articles using data from stock markets. This research
        shows that the asymmetric volatility between house prices moving up and down might
        account for the defensiveness of the housing market.
        In addition, the results inTableVindicate that theGJR-GARCHmodel performs better
        than GARCH, which does not incorporate asymmetric volatility, since the values of AIC
        and SBC are lower and the innovations are closer to white noise. Finally, the#p#分页标题#e#
        inappropriateness of the ARCH and GARCH models might be because they do not
        considerate asymmetric volatility, sinceg are negative. Therefore, when we consider the
        anti-leverage effect, the sum of estimated coefficients describing the relation between the
        conditional variance and the lagged error and lagged variance will decrease.
        Robustness test
        The results in Table V are obtained by assuming that the volatility of house price
        would only change with innovations. In this section, we proceed to test whether the
        asymmetric volatility can be influenced by the economic conditions by using the real
        Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and the interest rate of three-month Treasury Bills in
        the UK as proxy variables for the robustness test. These two variables are put into the
        variance equation of the GJR-GARCH (1,1) model, with the following results.
        As we can see in Table VI, although economic variables are incorporated in this
        model, asymmetric volatility still exists in the two markets, and since the coefficient g
        Figure 3.
        Returns and estimated
        conditional volatilities for
        the new house market
        Volatility of
        house prices
        87
        is also significantly negative, we can say there is still a anti-leverage effect in the UK
        housing market after controlling for the influence from macroeconomics.
        Conclusion
        This paper studies volatility properties in the UK house price series, in particular, to
        examine whether or not there is a leverage effect in the volatility of house price. To
        estimate the conditional volatility, the ARCH-type models are used, and to capture the
        leverage effect (asymmetric volatility effect), a GJR-GARCH model is used.
        The data are composed of UK nation-wide house prices from 1955 to 2005;
        comparing all house and new house price data. Empirical tests show that the
        coefficient representing the asymmetric feature of conditional variance is very
        significant, indicating that there is asymmetric volatility in the two housing markets.
        Furthermore, the results show that there are anti-leverage effects in both markets
        because when bad news is announced, the lagged error is negative and the variance
        will decrease. This is in contrast with the findings of empirical articles using data from
        stock markets. This research shows that the asymmetric volatility between house price
        movement might account for the defensiveness of the housing market.
        GJR-GARCH(1,1)
        Model All house New house
        Mean equation
        a0 0.83* 0.87*
        (0.35) (0.16)
        a1 0.52* 0.50*
        (0.05) (0.06)
        Variance equation
        v0 0.41* 0.56*
        (0.13) (0.11)
        a1 0.08* 0.05*
        (0.01) (0.00)
        b1 1.01* 1.02*
        (0.01) (0.01)
        g 20.19* 20.16*
        0.03 0.02
        Adj R-squared 0.39 0.30
        AIC 7.35 7.50
        SBC 7.44 7.69
        Q(20) 130.50* 31.15*
        Q2(20) 21.05 6.50
        Notes: Model, let yt denote the series of the differenced house price
        yt ¼ a0 þ a1yt21 þ 1t
        1t jVt21
        ~ jNð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þb1ht21 þa112t
        21 þgDt12t
        21
        * indicates significance at the 5 per cent level, where Dt21 is a dummy variable, when 1t21 , 0, then
        Dt21=1, otherwise, Dt21=0; numbers in parentheses are standard errors; Q(20) and Q2(20) are the
        Ljung-Box statistics based on the standardized residuals and the squared standardized residuals,
        respectively, up to the 20th order
        Table V.
        Empirical results of
        GJR-GARCH(1,1) model
        PM
        27,2
        88
        It is important to point out a limitation of this study, that house price series are difficult
        to construct because housing is not a homogeneous asset. Houses differ according to a
        variety of qualitative characteristics relating to their physical attributes, and so a good
        adjustment for quality change in the series is desirable. However, our study requires a
        relatively long-term data series for ARCH type analysis but the data we use are
        compiled by weighted averages. The limitation in quality adjustment could result in
        over-stating the possible fluctuation of the house price series. However, a good
        adjustment for quality change was not an option available in this study and this will
        leave further research.
        References
        Abraham, J.M. and Hendershott, P.H. (1996), “Bubbles in metropolitan housing markets”, Journal
        of Housing Research, Vol. 7, pp. 191-207.
        GJR-GARCH(1,1)
        Model All house New house
        Mean equation
        a0 1.16 * 1.49 *
        (0.14) (0.58)
        a1 0.53 * 0.50 *
        (0.05) (0.07)
        Variance equation
        v0 21.48 22.58
        (1.71) (2.54)
        a1 0.09 * 0.06
        (0.01) (0.03)
        a2 2156.43 29.69
        (105.16) (289.16)
        a3 0.69 0.71
        (0.35) * (0.43)
        b1 1.03 * 1.00 *
        (0.02) (0.02)
        g 20.30 * 20.17 *
        (0.05) 0.04
        Adj R-squared 0.38 0.29
        AIC 7.44 7.69
        SBC 7.57 7.82
        Q(20) 161.62 * 33.83 *
        Q2(20) 36.32 * 7.77
        Notes: Model, let yt denote the series of the differenced house price
        yt ¼ a0 þ a1yt21 þ 1t
        1t jVt21
        ~ jNð0; htÞ
        ht ¼ v0 þb1ht21 þa112t
        21 þa2DGDPt þa3it þgDt12t
        21
        * indicates significance at the 5 per cent level; where Dt21 is a dummy variable, when 1t21 , 0,
        Dt21=1, otherwise, Dt21=0; numbers in parentheses are standard errors. Q(20) and Q2 (20) are the
        Ljung-Box statistics based on the standardized residuals and the squared standardized residuals,
        respectively, up to the 20th order
        Table VI.
        GJR-GARCH model
        considering economic
        conditions
        Volatility of
        house prices
        89
        Black, F. (1976), Studies of Stock Price Volatility Changes. The 1976 Meetings of the Business and
        Economics Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, Alexandria, VA, pp. 177-81.
        Bollerslev, T. (1986), “Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity”, Journal of
        Econometrics, Vol. 31, pp. 307-28.
        Dolde, W. and Tirtitoglu, D. (2002), “Housing price volatility changes and their effects”, Real
        Estate Economics, Vol. 30, pp. 41-66.
        Drake, L. (1993), “Modelling UK house prices using cointegration: an application of the Johansen
        technique”, Applied Economics, Vol. 25, pp. 1225-8.
        Eitrheim, O. (1995), “Norwegian housing prices 1983 to 1992: a linear dynamic model”, mimeo,
        Central Bank of Norway, New York, NY.
        Engle, R.F. (1982), “Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance
        of United Kingdom inflation”, Econometrica, Vol. 50, pp. 987-1007.
        Giussani, B. and Hadjimatheou, G. (1990), “House prices: an econometrics model for the UK”, The
        APEX Centre Economics Discussion Paper, 90/1.
        Glosten, L.R., Jagannathan, R. and Runkle, D.E. (1993), “On the relation between the expected
        value and the volatility of the nominal excess return on stocks”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 48,
        pp. 1779-801.
        Heiborn, M. (1994), “Demographic factors and the demand for housing”, Working Paper 1994:30,
        Department of Economics, Uppsala University, Uppsala.
        Hendry, D.F. (1984), “Econometric modelling of house prices in the UK”, in Hendry, D.F. and
        Wallis, K.F. (Eds), Econometrics and Quantitative Economics, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.
        Kapur, B.K. (2006), “Financial liberalization and short-run housing price dynamics”, Economic
        Theory, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 649-75.
        Malpezzi, S. (2001), “The long-run price elasticity of supply of new residential construction in the
        United States and the United Kingdom”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 10,
        pp. 278-306.
        Meen, G.P. (1990), “The removal of mortgage market constraints and the implications for
        econometric modelling of UK house prices”, Oxford Bulletin Economics and Statistics,
        Vol. 52 No. 1, pp. 1-23.
        Miller, N. and Peng, L. (2006), “Exploring metropolitan housing price volatility”, Journal of Real
        Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 33, pp. 5-18.
        Phillips, P. and Perron, P. (1988), “Testing for a unit root in time series regression”, Biometrica,
        Vol. 75, pp. 335-46.
        Said, S. and Dickey, D. (1984), “Testing for unit roots in autoregressive-moving average models
        with unknown order”, Biometrica, Vol. 71, pp. 599-607.
        Tsai, I-C., Chen, M.-C. and Ma, T. (2008), “Modelling house price volatility in the United Kingdom
        by switching ARCH Models”, Applied Economics, forthcoming.
        Zakoian, J.M. (1994), “Threshold heteroskedastic models”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
        Control, Vol. 18, pp. 931-55.
        Corresponding author
        Ming-Chi Chen can be contacted at: mcchen@finance.nsysu.edu.tw
        PM
        27,2
        90
        To purchase reprints of this article please
        Or visit our web site for further details:

        此论文免费


        如果您有论文代写需求,可以通过下面的方式联系我们
        点击联系客服
        推荐内容
        可以看A片的网站
        <code id="0vk3o"><ol id="0vk3o"></ol></code><track id="0vk3o"></track>
        <p id="0vk3o"><strong id="0vk3o"><small id="0vk3o"></small></strong></p>

      2. <td id="0vk3o"></td>
          1. <pre id="0vk3o"></pre>